WWW.DISSERTATION.XLIBX.INFO
FREE ELECTRONIC LIBRARY - Dissertations, online materials
 
<< HOME
CONTACTS



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 8 |

«The Stability and Growth Pact will lead member countries to aim for cyclically balanced budgets. Until this steady state is reached, Europe will ...»

-- [ Page 1 ] --

ct

a

yP

lit ?

ce

bi an

is

nu

ta or

in

m

S na

tha

re

Mo SUMMARY

The Stability and Growth Pact will lead member countries to aim for

cyclically balanced budgets. Until this steady state is reached, Europe will

continue its efforts at deficit cutting. While so doing, politicians are less likely

to undertake the difficult labour market reforms that are really needed. Is further fiscal retrenchment wise? The paper reviews the reasons that have been advanced in favour of a Stability Pact and finds them wanting. The most serious justifications, such as the systemic risk of bank crisis following a government’s failure to service its debt, can be better dealt with in other ways: for example, by prudential limits on banks’ exposure to public debts.

Moreover, our analysis reveals that the macroeconomic costs of the Stability Pact, while sizeable, are not as dangerous as often believed. The costs will be barely visible once the steady state is reached. The true macroeconomic costs are front loaded; they concern the next few years, after a decade already dominated by convergence efforts.

— Barry Eichengreen and Charles Wyplosz Economic Policy April 1998 Printed in Great Britain © CEPR, CES, MSH, 1998.

67

STABILITY PACT

The Stability Pact:

more than a minor nuisance?

Barry Eichengreen and Charles Wyplosz IMF, University of California, Berkeley, CEPR and NBER; Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva, and CEPR

1. INTRODUCTION The Maastricht Treaty provides the institutional framework for Europe’s monetary union. Its essential features have been the subject of extensive discussion: these include the three-step transition, the creation of a European Central Bank, procedures for shaping the conduct of fiscal policy (the Excessive Deficit and Mutual Surveillance Procedures of Art. 103, 104 and 109) and the no-bailout rule prohibiting the ECB from acquiring public debt directly from the issuer (Art. 104 of the treaty and Art. 21 of the Protocol on the European System of Central Banks).

The one post-Maastricht element, finalized at the June 1997 meeting of the European Council in Amsterdam, is the Pact for Stability and Growth. 1 The pact clarifies the provisions of the Excessive Deficit Procedure. It calls for fiscal For help with data we thank Tamim Bayoumi, Herve Daudin, Paul De Grauwe, Tom Fernley, Morris Goldstein, Patrick Honohan, Alessandro Missale, Th. Papaspyrou, Ole Marius Tideman, Giuseppe Tullio, Bill White and Geoffrey Woglom. Xavier Debrun, Arjan Kadareja, Darren Lubotsky and Matthew Olson provided efficient research assistance. Financial support was provided by FNRS in Switzerland and the Center for German and European Studies of the University of California as well as the National Science Foundation in the United States. The opinions expressed are not necessarily those of the International Monetary Fund. Without implicating them in our conclusions, for helpful comments and guidance we would like to thank Donogh McDonald, the members of the Economic Policy Panel, our discussants, the journal’s referees and David Begg.

1 The ‘growth’ part was added at the request of the French authorities as a face-saving device after they were forced to soften their previous opposition.

68 BARRY EICHENGREEN AND CHARLES WYPLOSZ

positions to be balanced or in surplus in normal times so that automatic stabilizers can operate. It urges stronger surveillance of medium-term fiscal positions with the goal of providing an early warning signal that the 3% reference value for budget deficits is at risk. It clarifies the conditions under which participants in the monetary union will be allowed to exceed the 3% deficit ceiling without being determined to have an excessive deficit. Countries will be automatically exempt only if their GDPs have declined by 2% and the excess deficit is temporary and small. Those in which GDP declines by between 0.75% and 2% could also be exempt, but only with the concurrence of the Council of Ministers. Countries with even milder recessions will be found to have an excessive deficit and forced to make mandatory deposits that are transformed into fines if the fiscal excess is not eliminated within two years.

Although this new transparency is welcome, it also reveals a more restrictive set of provisions than those laid down by the Maastricht Treaty. The treaty says only that the general government deficit may not exceed its reference value (3% of GDP) unless the deficit has declined significantly and continuously to where it is close to that reference value, or the excess of the reference value is only exceptional and temporary and the deficit remains close to the reference value. It says nothing, in other words, about the size of the output decline producing that exceptional and temporary excess deficit, or the period over which it must occur. In this sense the Stability Pact implies less flexibility than the Maastricht Treaty.

The Stability Pact has not received the same systematic analysis as other aspects of the Maastricht Treaty. 2 Providing that analysis is our purpose in this paper.

Our conclusion is that the Stability Pact will have some effect. Governments will adjust their fiscal policies just enough to avoid incurring fines. EU authorities for their part will give countries just enough leeway to avoid having to fine them.





Actually imposing fines would worsen conditions in the adversely affected member state, lead to recrimination and deal a blow to EU solidarity. Actually incurring fines would subject a government to serious embarrassment and loss of political face.

Hence, the pact is likely to alter fiscal behaviour just enough to avoid these outcomes.

This will reduce the extent of automatic stabilization. Estimates based on historical data suggest that automatic stabilization may increase in the output gap, but by only a fraction of a percentage point. Hence the ‘minor nuisance’ of the title.

But even a fraction of a percentage point on the growth rate can become important when allowed to accumulate over time. Our simulations suggest that, after accumulation over the last two decades, levels of real output would have ended 5% lower in France and the UK, and 9% lower in Italy.

2 See, however, Artis and Winkler (1997), Beetsma and Uhlig (1997) and Buti et al. (1997).

69

STABILITY PACT

The critical question, therefore, is how hamstrung automatic stabilizers will be.

Will the Stability Pact weaken them as much in the future as it would have in the past, had it been superimposed on actual experience? The answer hinges on how far below the 3% ceiling budget deficits are when Stage III begins. If budgets move significantly into surplus relative to past experience, there is no reason why automatic stabilizers will be much affected. But in the present climate, where electorates lack the appetite for further spending cuts, significantly smaller deficits require significantly faster growth. The danger is thus that the Stability Pact will divert effort from the fundamental reforms needed to step up the pace.

In  particular, without fundamental labour market reform, Europe will fail to grow  by at least 3–31% a year, and deficits will not decline. The Stability Pact _ 2 will  grow more binding, and the operation of Europe’s automatic stabilizers will remain feeble, increasing the volatility of output, further depressing growth, and making the provisions of the pact even more binding than before. Through the operation of this vicious spiral, Europe could be condemned to a low-level equilibrium trap.

Our view is that leaders have a fixed amount of political capital that they can allocate to politically costly fiscal reform or politically costly labour market reform.

To the extent that they invest in one, they have fewer resources left to devote to the other. In practice, they are likely to compromise, doing a little of each. For example, those European countries that have made the most progress in eliminating budget deficits and increasing labour market flexibility (Ireland and Finland spring to mind) have allocated their adjustment effort evenly to fiscal consolidation and labour market reform.

Our conclusion will be that the Stability Pact may have some slight benefits in terms of fiscal discipline, but may have significant costs, both in diverting political effort from more fundamental problems and indeed in making those fundamental problems worse than before.

2. WHAT THE STABILITY PACT SAYS

The Stability Pact consists of two Council regulations, one on the Excessive Deficit Procedure and another on surveillance, and a European Council resolution that provides guidance to the Council and member states on the application of the pact.

The two Council regulations have the force of law. They clarify the meaning of the Maastricht Treaty’s provisions regarding excessive deficits, in particular in respect of exceptional and temporary circumstances under which the 3% reference value for the general government deficit can be exceeded without a determination that the deficit is excessive. In addition, under the pact’s provisions, participants in the monetary union commit themselves to a medium-term budgetary stance ‘close to balance or surplus’.

70 BARRY EICHENGREEN AND CHARLES WYPLOSZ

The pact will consider a deficit in excess of 3% to be exceptional if a country’s GDP declines by at least 2% in the year in question. In addition, a recession in which real GDP declines by less than 2% but more than 0.75% may qualify with the concurrence of the Council. The country will have to show that its recession was exceptional in terms of its abruptness or in relation to past output trends. Countries with annual output declines smaller than 0.75% will not be able to claim exceptional circumstances. These provisions thus clarify the Maastricht Treaty’s clauses regarding the exceptional circumstances under which the 3% reference value can be exceeded without leading to the determination of an excessive deficit.

The pact also includes provisions concerning further exemptions. While countries are obliged to correct excessive deficits ‘as quickly as possible after their emergence’ and to ‘launch the corrective budgetary adjustments they deem necessary without delay’, they will probably be able to run deficits in excess of 3% of GDP for at least two years in a row without incurring fines. The Commission will receive definitive data that a country’s deficit in year t exceeded 3% around March of year t + 1. By the end of May it will have issued a recommendation for eliminating that excess in accordance with Article 103(4). The country will then have to take corrective action such that the excess is eliminated by year t + 2. If no corrective action is taken by the end of year t + 1, financial sanctions will be imposed. But presumably corrective action that will eliminate the excess in year t + 2 will suffice to eliminate this threat.

Thus, two successive years of budget deficits in excess of 3% (and possibly more – see below) will be permitted.

Moreover, the passage specifying these time limits ends with the qualifying phrase ‘unless there are special circumstances’. The nature of those special circumstances is not specified. But presumably a country like Finland in the early 1990s, which suffered budgetary difficulties reflecting special circumstances largely beyond its control, would be allowed to take even longer to bring its deficit back down to 3%.

Nor does the pact clarify a third provision of the Excessive Deficit Procedure, that the budget must remain ‘close’ to the reference value to avoid the determination of an excessive deficit.

Sanctions, when required, will take the form of non-remunerated deposits, which start at 0.2% of GDP and rise by one-tenth of the excess deficit up to a maximum of 0.5% of GDP. Additional deposits will be required each year until the excessive deficit is corrected. If the excess is not corrected within two years, the deposit will be converted into a fine; otherwise it will be returned.

Thus, a careful reading does not imply that fines will be levied as soon as budget deficits exceed 3% of GDP. The pact is rather more flexible. It allows temporary exemptions for countries experiencing ‘severe’ recessions. More generally, it allows time for excessive deficits to be corrected; in the case of undefined ‘special circumstances’ it allows unspecified amounts of time. Clearly, one needs to think harder about the political economy of EU policy making to forecast how strictly the fines and sanctions of the Stability Pact will be applied.

71

STABILITY PACT

3. RATIONALES FOR THE STABILITY PACT

For an argument favouring the Stability Pact to convince, it must satisfy three conditions. The effect on which it hinges must be first order (on the principle that controversial policies with potentially important side-effects should not be adopted in response to negligible problems). It must have Europe-wide repercussions (on the principle that, if its effects are purely national, there is no justification for a Europewide response). And, arguably, it must be a consequence of monetary union rather than a corollary of European integration (on the principle that the Excessive Deficit Procedure and the rest of the Maastricht Treaty apply to member states whether in or out of the monetary union, whereas the sanctions of the Stability Pact apply specifically to participants in EMU). 3

3.1. To prevent inflationary debt bailouts



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 8 |


Similar works:

«S E N I A F E B R I CA Securitizing Terrorism in Southeast Asia Accounting for the Varying Responses of Singapore and Indonesia A B S T R AC T This article explains the variable success after the September 11, 2001, attacks of the securitization of terrorism in two ASEAN member states, Singapore and Indonesia. The two countries are selected because of the differences in their government characteristics and their domestic politics. The article argues that differences in the nature of the...»

«BANGLADESH 2014 INTERNATIONAL RELIGIOUS FREEDOM REPORT Executive Summary The constitution designates Islam as the state religion, but states the nation is a secular state that “shall ensure equal status and equal rights in the practice of the Hindu, Buddhist, Christian, and other religions.” It affirms secularism is based on the elimination of: granting any religion political status; abuse of religion for any purpose; and “discrimination against, or persecution of, persons practicing a...»

«Johnson | Chinese Leadership Under Xi Jinping A Pragmatic Approach to Power Chinese Leadership Under President Xi Jinping An Interview with Christopher K. Johnson In this interview, Christopher Johnson discusses some of the earlier formative experiences that may have shaped the Chinese leader Xi Jinping’s political beliefs and policy preferences. Johnson’s measured analysis of Xi’s approach to power and the Chinese Communist Party (CCP)’s dependency on public approval provides valuable...»

«Curriculum Vitae 1. Personal Data: ‫דר עקירב אסנת‬ Name in Hebrew:Akirav Osnat, Ph.D. Name in English: 2. Education Certificates and Degrees: From To Department Institute Education Tel Aviv University 1988-1991 Political Science First Degree Tel Aviv University 1992-1994 Political Science Second Degree Hebrew University, 1995-2003 Political Science Third Degree Jerusalem UCSD, USA. 2007 Political Science Post Doc 3. Title of Master's Thesis: The causes of the formal activity of...»

«'The views expressed are those of the author and do not reflect the official policy or position of the US Air Force, Department of Defense or the US Government.' USAFA Harmon Memorial Lecture #35 United States Policy Vis-a-vis Korea, 1850-1950 Professor John Edward Wilz, 1992 Let me begin by observing that my distinguished colleague at Indiana University, Rohert H. Ferrell, used to rattle doctoral candidates who were defending dissertations by asking, while flashing an impish grin, What is the...»

«Individuals and the Significance of Affect: Foreign Policy Variation in the Middle East Brent E. Sasley Department of Political Science McGill University, Montreal November 2006 A thesis submitted to McGill University in partial fulfillment ofthe requirements of the degree of Doctor ofPhilosophy (Ph.D.) © Copyright Brent E. Sasley, 2006 Library and Bibliothèque et 1+1 Archives Canada Archives Canada Published Heritage Direction du Branch Patrimoine de l'édition 395 Wellington Street 395, rue...»

«Queensland Environmental Offsets Policy Significant Residual Impact Guideline Nature Conservation Act 1992 Environmental Protection Act 1994 Marine Parks Act 2004 December 2014 Prepared by: Biodiversity Integration and Offsets, Ecosystem Outcomes,, Department of Environment and Heritage Protection © State of Queensland, 2014. The Queensland Government supports and encourages the dissemination and exchange of its information. The copyright in this publication is licensed under a Creative...»

«School of Global Policy & Strategy (GPS) University of California, San Diego BARBARA F. WALTER La Jolla, CA 92093 (858) 822-0775 bfwalter@ucsd.edu (Updated April 2016) PROFESSIONAL APPOINTMENTS University of California, San Diego (UCSD) La Jolla, CA Professor of Political Science, School of Global Policy & Strategy (GPS) and adjunct Professor, Department of Political Science, 2008 present. Associate Dean, GPS, 2011 – 2014 Full Professor, GPS, 2008-present Associate Professor, GPS, 2002 –...»

«Baldev Raj Nayar Department of Political Science, McGill University, 855 Sherbrooke Street West, Montreal, Quebec, Canada H3A 2T7 E-mail: baldev.nayar@mcgill.ca TEL: (514) 398 – 4800; (613) 792-1354 (H) Place and Date of Birth Gujrat, Punjab, India October 26, 1931 EDUCATION 1963 University of Chicago Ph.D. 1959 University of Chicago M.A. 1956 Panjab University M.A. 1953 Panjab University B.A. ACADEMIC POSITIONS 1994 – present McGill University: Emeritus Professor of Political Science 1971...»

«THE CEIBA TREE AS A MULTIVOCAL SIGNIFIER: Afro-Cuban Symbolism, Political Performance, and Urban Space in the Cuban Republic Joseph Hartman, M.A. Student, Department of Art Education and Art History, University of North Texas INTRODUCTION: AFRO-CUBAN SYMBOLISM, POLITICAL PERFORMANCE, AND URBAN SPACE Ivor Miller’s article “Religious Symbolism in Cuban Political Performance” brings to light an interesting phenomenon: twentieth-century Cuban politicians used symbols that were associated with...»

«COMING TO TERMS WITH 21ST CENTURY BRITISH POLITICS: AN INTERVIEW WITH TOBY LITT JOURNAL OF ENGLISH STUDIES VOLUME 9 (2011), 277-286 COMING TO TERMS WITH 21ST CENTURY BRITISH POLITICS: AN INTERVIEW WITH TOBY LITT BETSABÉ NAVARRO ROMERO* Santiago de Compostela University ABSTRACT. English novelist and short story writer, Toby Litt is the author of the novels Beatniks: An English Road Movie (1997), Corpsing (2000), Deadkidsongs (2001), Finding Myself (2003), Ghost Story (2004), Hospital (2007), I...»

«Biased Recommendations from Unbiased Experts Wonsuk Chung and Rick Harbaugh∗ This Version: August 2016 Abstract When can an expert be trusted to provide useful advice? We develop and experimentally test a simplified recommendation game where an expert recommends one of two actions to a decision maker who can take one of the actions or neither. Consistent with predictions from the cheap talk literature, we find that recommendations are persuasive in that they induce actions benefiting the...»





 
<<  HOME   |    CONTACTS
2016 www.dissertation.xlibx.info - Dissertations, online materials

Materials of this site are available for review, all rights belong to their respective owners.
If you do not agree with the fact that your material is placed on this site, please, email us, we will within 1-2 business days delete him.