WWW.DISSERTATION.XLIBX.INFO
FREE ELECTRONIC LIBRARY - Dissertations, online materials
 
<< HOME
CONTACTS



Pages:   || 2 |

«Jean-Pierre Danthine: Reconciling price and financial stability Speech by Mr Jean-Pierre Danthine, Member of the Governing Board of the Swiss ...»

-- [ Page 1 ] --

Jean-Pierre Danthine: Reconciling price and financial stability

Speech by Mr Jean-Pierre Danthine, Member of the Governing Board of the Swiss National

Bank, at the University of Zurich, Zurich, 24 January 2012.

* * *

I would like to thank Pierre Monnin, Anna Faber and Adriel Jost for their invaluable support in drafting

this paper. I also thank Rita Kobel, Peter Kuster, Reto Nyfeller, Dewet Moser and Angelo Ranaldo for

their insightful comments.

It is a great pleasure for me to be with you today at the University of Zurich to discuss an issue that the recent financial crisis has exposed as a major challenge to central banks;

namely how they can best contribute to ensuring financial stability while pursuing price stability as a primary mandate.1 Before I do this, however, let me say a few words on another dimension of stability: institutional stability. As you are all aware, the Swiss National Bank (SNB) recently experienced an unfortunate event which has few, if any, historical precedents.

On a personal level, I deeply regret the resignation of Philipp Hildebrand, under whose leadership the SNB steered Swiss monetary policy over the last two years. On an institutional level, however, I would like to stress that the SNB’s institutional strength is the result of teamwork, not only between the board members, but across the Bank as a whole.

The SNB’s culture is one of excellence and of service. It is the product of a long history and many generations of leaders. It remains as strong as ever. Despite the difficult conditions and the unusual challenges that have characterized the last two years, all important monetary policy decisions have been reached by consensus, a consensus which emerged from in-depth and intensive analyses and discussions. The current course of Swiss monetary policy, particularly the decision to introduce a minimum exchange rate, is the result of a deep-rooted consensus of this kind. The SNB will thus continue to enforce the minimum rate with the utmost determination and remains prepared to buy foreign currency in unlimited quantities. The Swiss franc is still highly valued, but it should depreciate further in the future.

Let me now return to my topic. I will start by presenting general pre-crisis assessments of the state of monetary policy and will then examine how central banks’ policies may have contributed to the financial crisis. After considering these issues, I will be in position to assess the alternative courses of action available to central banks in general, and the SNB in particular, to derive principles for a future in which financial and price stability are better reconciled with one another.

I. The Great Moderation: a success of monetary policy?

Let me start by considering the state of many developed economies, to include Switzerland, before the onset of the crisis. In contrast with the episodes of high inflation which prevailed in the 1970’s, rates of inflation were subsequently stable and low for some twenty years. This period, which is commonly referred to as the “Great Moderation”, was also characterized by low real GDP volatility and low interest rates. Slide 1 illustrates these developments in the cases of the United States and Switzerland in this period.

Though there is no definitive analysis of the causes of the “Great Moderation”, monetary policy is regularly cited as a contributing factor.2 This accords well with observations that 1 This order of priorities is in line with the National Bank Act, article 5, which clearly states that “ensuring price stability” is the SNB’s primary goal while it should also “contribute to the stability of the financial system”.

2 Other commonly cited causes are: i) financial deepening resulting from developments in the financial markets in the 1980–90’s such as options, hedging tools, etc.; ii) less and more stable government regulation and taxation; iii) luck.

1 BIS central bankers’ speeches major progress had been made in identifying the determinants of inflation, understanding the importance of central bank independence and therefore in improving the conduct of monetary policy. At the methodological level, these developments are generally linked to the concept of “inflation-targeting”3 and summarized in a class of macroeconomic models, which Marvin Goodfriend and Robert King4 have named “the New Neoclassical Synthesis”. This label tells of an approach that combined key elements of Keynesian and classical thinking.

While the new models made conditional forecasting possible and permitted scientifically appropriate policy evaluations, they only included primitive financial sectors. In their current state, they therefore cannot address issues of financial stability or the link between low interest rates and financial excesses.

II. The recent financial crisis: are central banks the culprits?

The recent financial crisis has thrown the positive pre-crisis perceptions of modern monetary policy into question. Indeed, many analysts now attribute a certain degree of responsibility for the financial crisis to central banks, in sharp contrast with the typically benevolent assessment of their contributions to the “Great Moderation”. Two main lines of argument support claims that central banks were contributed to the crisis, as Slide 2 illustrates. The first is that the precepts of the “inflation-targeting” paradigm were misapplied and that these policy errors have contributed to, or have directly caused, the crisis. The second is that the paradigm itself is deficient, or at least incomplete. Indeed, even when central banks conduct monetary policy optimally, according to the “inflation-targeting” mantra, it is a mistake for them not to recognise that a long period of low interest rates may encourage financial intermediaries to take increased risks with negative consequences for systemic stability.





One clear proponent of the first argument is John B. Taylor. Taylor has argued that the Federal Reserve contributed to the crisis by setting interest rates too low prior to 2007. Although price stability was achieved, monetary policy in the United States was, in his view, inappropriately conducted, given the level of inflation and the size of the output gap, as attested by significant deviations from the “Taylor rule”, a benchmark he first proposed in 1993.5 The “Taylor rule” recommends that central banks systematically adjust nominal interest rates in response to macroeconomic developments and inflation movements, but, between 2002 and 2005, they were lower than the “Taylor rule” advised, as Slide 3 illustrates. According to Taylor,6 monetary policy may have been too expansionary, certainly in the United States and the Euro area. Taylor even suggests that, if central banks had set higher interest rates in this period, the subsequent housing bubble and the global financial crisis might have been avoided.7 According to this view, the crisis stemmed from a misapplication of the “inflationtargeting” precept. The underlying models may be unable to explain why an excessively accommodative policy would lead to a financial crisis. The episode does not, however, imply that the entire monetary policy paradigm has to be revisited, nor that financial stability is incompatible with price stability.

3 The SNB does not describe its approach as “inflation targeting” as it differs somewhat from classic “inflation targeting”. See http://www.snb.ch/en/iabout/monpol for further details.

4 Goodfriend and King (1997).

5 Taylor (1993).

6 Interpretations of the “Taylor rule” can be ambiguous. Interestingly, the formula produces quite different results depending on whether it includes core or headline inflation and how the output gap is measured. It also omits factors such as widening credit spreads, the role of time-varying parameters and the risk of deflation, particularly between 2002 and 2004. See, for example, Bernanke (2010) and Kohn (2007).

7 Taylor (2009).

2 BIS central bankers’ speeches Slide 4 illustrates the “supply shock” hypothesis. Here, the crux of the argument is that monetary policy was too expansionary because the impact of supply shocks on prices was underestimated. This, in turn, prompted miscalculations of the output gap. As one can see, in the United Kingdom and in Switzerland, the prices of those goods which were most influenced by imports increased far more slowly than those of services, which were less import-dependent. One plausible explanation for this is that the availability of cheap imports from Asia (or Eastern Europe) acted as a positive supply shock, thus reducing the relative price of imports. If the supply shock had been temporary, it would have provoked lower transitory inflation and the optimal monetary policy response would have been to do nothing, except to let the economic forces at play re-establish an equilibrium and normal inflation levels.8 In recent decades, however, the pressures associated with globalization have borne greater resemblance to a permanent series of shocks. As these shocks were interpreted as temporary, they were disregarded from a policy perspective, which, it is argued, caused monetary policies to be excessively expansionary.

Both of these views suggest that central banks could have potentially helped prevent the crisis by setting higher interest rates and that they should have done so if the “inflationtargeting” precepts had been fully understood and optimally followed. In both cases, however, the underlying models would have predicted that such policy failures would have prompted overproduction and excessive rates of inflation, rather than a financial crisis.

The third hypothesis I would like to discuss is the theory of the “risk-taking channel”. This newer line of argument is that, even if monetary policy was optimally conducted before the crisis, the prevailing low interest rates provided fertile ground for miscalculation and excessive risk-taking by financial intermediaries, thus contributing to the crisis. According to this view, the “inflation-targeting” paradigm itself is deficient in the sense that it does not take into account the negative externality of a policy exclusively aimed at price stability imposes on financial stability. In Claudio Borio and Haibin Zhu’s9 terms, “changes in policy rates have an impact on either risk perception or risk-tolerance and hence on the degree of risk in portfolios, on the pricing of assets, and on the price and the non-price terms of the extension of funding”. In other words, a long period of low interest rates drives financial intermediaries to take increased risks. Empirically, there is a growing body of evidence to indicate that a channel of this kind exists.10 There are three main versions of the “risk-taking channel”. Every one of them suggests that, while low interest rates might be the natural consequence of price stability, they may ultimately compromise financial stability. The first hypothesis, is that hedge-fund and wealth managers, who tend to be paid according to the nominal returns on their investments, might be prone to taking additional, possibly excessive, risks when interest rates are low and, as a result, they might receive lower levels of compensation.11 To the best of my knowledge, empirical studies which support or dismiss this claim have been yet to be carried out.

The second hypothesis12 is that low interest rates increase the value of the collateral backing up loans. Banks thus have less incentive to monitor their clients’ loans.13 This view is empirically better documented, but the supporting evidence is ambiguous.14 8 Bean (2006).

9 Borio and Zhu (2008).

10 See, for example, Altunbas, Gambacorta and Marqués-Ibáñez (2010).

11 Rajan (2005) 12 Dell’Ariccia, Laeven and Marquez (2010) 13 Note that this theory closely resembles Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler’s “financial accelerator” model.

However, in this model the increase in collateral value prompts investors to borrow more whereas in the model of the “risk-taking channel”, increased collateral value induces banks to monitor their existing loans less.

3 BIS central bankers’ speeches Finally, the third hypothesis is that banks with access to cheaper external funding increase their leverage to achieve higher returns on equity. This change in banks’ balance sheet structure tends to make the banking sector more fragile. There is some evidence to support this argument. For example, Slide 5 reports the results of simulating how banks in the United States adjust their external funding to changes in monetary policy. It suggests that when central banks increase interest rates, banks significantly decrease their external funding for the next two years or so.15 The “Taylor rule”, the “supply shock” hypothesis and the “risk-taking channel” theory all have one common feature. Every one of them acknowledges the possibility that interest rates may have been too low prior to the crisis, though their proponents may disagree as to whether, or to what extent, this was the result of a policy or paradigm failure. There is also consensus that this may have contributed to the financial instability that followed, although only the theory of the “risk-taking channel” clearly suggests how this would have come about.

III. “Leaning against the wind”: an unfavourable trade-off between financial stability and output growth If interest rates were indeed too low in the pre-crisis years, it would appear that by raising them central banks could have helped avoid, or at least contain, the crisis. When this calls for deviations from otherwise optimal policy, one talks of “leaning against the wind”. In economic upturns, this would involve central banks setting higher interest rates than would be necessary to achieve price stability alone. The objective would be to avoid the overvaluation of assets, to constrain excessively risky behaviour on the part of financial intermediaries and hence to prevent bubbles from emerging, or at least to reduce their size.

In contrast, Alan Greenspan was widely credited for supporting a “clean up after bubbles” approach. This basically involves central banks actively sustaining the economy after an asset price bubble has burst, rather than using monetary policy to try to prevent the bubble from developing in the first place. The rationale for this approach is that it is more costeffective overall, as bubbles are very hard to identify. Erroneously implemented “leaning against the wind” policies could well impose significant economic costs with no real subsequent benefit.



Pages:   || 2 |


Similar works:

«Swisher 1 Reigniting the Light: Reaching Catholic Young Adults in the Digital World Let’s Start from the Top As a church, we have come a long way with youth ministry programs since the 1970s, growing and adapting to the needs of our youth. This, too, applies to campus ministry programs within our Catholic schools. Administrators are beginning to understand the importance of developing one's faith during adolescence, alongside academics and extra-curricular activities; the need to live one's...»

«Henkilöstön perehdytyskansio käyttötavaraosastoille Case: Suur-Seudun Osuuskauppa Prisma Lohja Maaniitty, Heini 2009 Lohja Laurea -ammattikorkeakoulu Laurea Lohja Henkilöstön perehdytyskansio käyttötavaraosastoille Case: Suur-Seudun Osuuskauppa Prisma Lohja Heini Maaniitty Liiketalouden koulutusohjelma Opinnäytetyö Toukokuu, 2009 Laurea–ammattikorkeakoulu Tiivistelmä Laurea Lohja Liiketalouden koulutusohjelma Palveluliiketoiminta ja asiakassuhdehallinta Heini Maaniitty...»

«Application for accreditation of PhD program in Applied microand nano systems at Vestfold University College Report from the expert committee The report on the application for PhD examination accreditation in Anvendte mikroog nanosystemer at Vestfold University College is hereby delivered by the appointed expert committee to NOKUT. The report is based on the application submitted by Vestfold University College on 01.02.2009, requested supplements to this application submitted on 30.10.2009, and...»

«The Journal of Specialised Translation Issue 1 January 2004 Jorge Díaz Cintas University of Surrey Roehampton, London Subtitling: the long journey to academic acknowledgement ABSTRACT The present article is part of a wider translation project from Spanish carried out by Juan Abad, Judith Harling, Yuka Miyakita, Mark Seager and Christina Wiggins, students at the University of Surrey Roehampton. Audiovisual translation seems to have been absent from academic exchanges on translation until very...»

«PHILIP LYTTON The first legitimate theatre entrepreneur to successfully establish a full-time moving theatre show in Australia, beginning in 1907, Philip Lytton and his wife, actress Madge Hope, were by 1914 operating three touring companies, around the Antipodes. In 1903 he co-founded The Player, an industry magazine which later became The Theatre Magazine. Two of the plays most associated with Lytton during the 1910s were The Girl from Outback (1912) and The Waybacks (1915), with the latter...»

«Lancaster University Department of Linguistics and Modern English Language CLSL Centre for Language in Social Life http://www.ling.lancs.ac.uk/groups/clsl/home.htm Working Papers Series http://www.ling.lancs.ac.uk/pubs/clsl/wpapers.htm Working Paper No. 105 From Linguistic Molehills to Social Mountains? Introducing Moral Panics about Language by Sally Johnson 1999 All rights reserved. This document is placed on the Internet solely in order to make it freely available to the wider research...»

«Paper to Appear in a Special Issue on Intelligent Systems/Tools In Training And Life-Long Learning in the International Journal of Continuing Engineering Education and Life-Long Learning (eds.: Riichiro Mizoguchi and Piet A.M. Kommers) Lifelong Learning Ñ More Than Training Gerhard Fischer Center for LifeLong Learning & Design (L3D) Department of Computer Science and Institute of Cognitive Science University of Colorado, Boulder 1. INTRODUCTION 3 2. PROBLEMS IN THE INFORMATION AGE 4 3....»

«Quanta Magazine Series: Janna Levin’s Theory of Doing Everything Janna Levin’s Theory of Doing Everything The astrophysicist, conceptual writer and host of standing-room-only scientific soirees at a repurposed factory in Brooklyn sees science as a powerful force in culture. https://www.quantamagazine.org/20160505-janna-levins-theory-of-doing-everything/ May 5, 2016 Quanta Magazine Béatrice de Géa for Quanta Magazine By Natalie Wolchover The astrophysicist and author Janna Levin has two...»

«Water today, water tomorrow November 2013 Final determination of Thames Water’s IDoK application www.ofwat.gov.uk Final determination of Thames Water’s IDoK application About this document We have decided to reject the proposed additional increase in prices by Thames Water for its customers in 2014-15. This document sets out our final determination including the reasons for this decision. In making our decisions, we want to be as transparent as we can with all stakeholders about how we have...»

«FINANCIAL FLAGSHIP INCREASING ACCESS TO CREDIT THROUGH REFORMING SECURED TRANSACTIONS IN THE MENA REGION ALEJANDRO ALVAREZ DE LA CAMPA * JUNE 2010 The World Bank * Alejandro Alvarez de la Campa, Global Product Leader for IFC’s Secured Transactions and Collateral Registries Program, World Bank Group. The author wishes to gratefully acknowledge the inputs provided by Murat Sultanov and Angana Shah and the assistance and guidance of Roberto Rocha in the preparation of this paper. The author is...»

«WAKO Tatami Sports General Rules WAKO Rules of Tatami Sports – General Rules Table of Contents Art. 1. Officials 4 4 Art. 1.1 Chairman of the Appeal Board 4 Art. 1.2 Tournament Committee 4 Art. 1.3 Chairman of Tatami Sports 4 Art. 1.4 Referees 4 Art. 1.5 Judges 5 Art. 1.5.1 Referees / Judges 6 Art. 1.6 Time Keeper 6 Art. 1.7 Score Keeper 6 Art. 1.8 Special Note 6 Art. 2. Safety equipment 6 Art. 2.1 Head protection 6 Art. 2.2 Gloves 6 Art. 2.2.1 Gloves for Semi-Contact 7 Art. 2.2.2 Gloves for...»

«Revista de Literatura, 2015, enero-junio, vol. LXXVII, n.o 153, págs. 47-73, ISSN: 0034-849X doi: 10.3989/revliteratura.2015.01.002 Hagiografía y censura en el teatro clásico Hagiography and Censorship in Theater of the Golden Age Héctor Urzáiz Tortajada Universidad de Valladolid RESUMEN Se estudia la censura de 24 comedias manuscritas de temática religiosa, sobre todo hagiográfica, fechadas entre 1600-1745; la mayoría son obras o autores poco conocidos: La loca del cielo, El hijo del...»





 
<<  HOME   |    CONTACTS
2016 www.dissertation.xlibx.info - Dissertations, online materials

Materials of this site are available for review, all rights belong to their respective owners.
If you do not agree with the fact that your material is placed on this site, please, email us, we will within 1-2 business days delete him.