WWW.DISSERTATION.XLIBX.INFO
FREE ELECTRONIC LIBRARY - Dissertations, online materials
 
<< HOME
CONTACTS



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 7 |

«Darius Mehri Department of Sociology 510 Barrows Hall University of California Berkeley, CA 94720 1 Abstract The Asian economic crash of 1997 lead to ...»

-- [ Page 1 ] --

Restructuring in the Toyota Keiretsu during the Asian Financial Crash:

An Ethnographic Perspective into Neo-liberal Reforms and the Varieties of

Capitalism

Darius Mehri

Department of Sociology

510 Barrows Hall

University of California

Berkeley, CA 94720

1

Abstract

The Asian economic crash of 1997 lead to widespread restructuring of corporate

organizations in Japan. This paper uses ethnographic field work and historical

documents to examine how this played out inside one company, Toyota, when management implemented a restructuring plan to improve the profitability of its companies during the period of 1996 to 1999. The restructuring policies are discussed within the framework of the varieties of capitalism debate. A hallmark of the current discussion on Japanese organizations is that Japan is converging toward the American model of capitalism. I argue that although Japanese companies have adapted to worsening economic conditions by incorporating neo-liberal market reforms, restructuring during the Asian crash reveals that changes in the Toyota organization were based on hybrid policies that fused both liberal and coordinated market economics within the context of the unique institutions of Japanese welfare corporatism.

2 Introduction Since the rise of Japan as an economic power in the 1960s, social scientists have been fascinated by the inner workings of Japanese capitalism. At the core of these concerns was an interest in studying organizations and whether, as the first Asian industrial nation, Japan was in the process of converging on the Western model. It was believed that as technology diffused throughout the industrial nations it would be the driving force behind producing similar organizations and institutions (Kerr, Dunlop, Harbison, and Myers 1960;

Marx 1976). Dore (1973) engaged in the convergence debate through an ethnographic comparative analysis of Japanese and British factories to show marked differences in recruiting, training, managing, motivating and rewarding workers. Dore was the first to claim “welfare corporatism”, an institutionalized system of social support institutions, as the model adopted by Japanese companies compared to the “market individualism” as experienced in Britain. He saw significant advantages to the Japanese model of welfare corporatism particularly in the realm of reciprocal labor management relationships and at the time, it was a model in which Britain was converging toward.

Cole (1979) addressed convergence theory through a multi-method historical analysis of workers in Yokohama and Detroit. He explored borrowing of personnel management practices and the process of adapting foreign innovations to Japanese organizational needs. Cole saw convergence on some important institutions, such as education and common technologies, but divergence when the two countries “developed along their own paths based on

–  –  –

Another stream of theorizing approached the understanding of Japanese organizations through a cultural interpretation. Abegglen (1958) initiated the approach with a discussion of how culture influences the uniqueness of Japanese institutions. He claimed long-term employee commitment to a firm in Japan is based on mutual obligations between managers and employees where the seniority based reward system is linked to service to the firm. Rohlen (1974) engaged in a similar discussion albeit with a Weberian theoretical frame - his analysis emphasized the cultural meaning in the daily behavior of bank employees. The conclusions of these studies are based on the assumption of historical continuity and therefore it is understood that Japanese organizations have a unique trajectory and are not converging on the Western model. Cole (1971) claimed to split the cultural and convergence perspective by arguing that functional alternatives have allowed the Japanese to create structural arrangements to solve common problems in industrial societies.

The pressure of globalization has lead to a reframing of the convergence debate. A flourishing of technology and a wave of new organizational techniques, such as supplier-client relations, just-in-time manufacturing and team production, has provided the means in which organizations in different nations develop collaborative relationships. If technology is providing the means in which organizations can become “global”, the liberalization of the international economy has provided the force behind the movement. The ideology behind liberalization is neo-liberalism that is defined by Harvey (2005) as “a theory of political economic practices that proposes that human well-being can best be advanced by liberating individual entrepreneurial freedoms and skills within an institutional

–  –  –

trade” (p. 2). It is believed that international institutions are providing the structural dynamic to diffuse neo-liberal social, economic and cultural-ideological changes around the world to force nations to convergence on free markets and free trade (Chase-Dunn, Kawano, and Brewer 2000; Robinson 2004; Woods 2006).

The acceptance of neo-liberal ideology is dependent on nations that are predisposed to the Anglo-American model of shareholder value that are based on equity based finance, an emphasis on profitability over growth and fluid external labor markets (Fligstein 1990). A stark contrast is the stakeholder model found in Japan and Germany that features tightly connected industrial and financial networks, growth over profits and internal labor markets (Ahmadjian and Robbins 2005; Hall and Soskice 2001). With the ascension of neo-liberal ideology and the perceived notion that marketization and privatization are solutions to economic decline, to what extent has globalization influenced Japanese welfare corporatism - a system that has been placed under considerable economic strain in recent years?





The economic downturn in Japan began with the stock market crash of 1989 when stocks lost 60 percent of their value and commercial real estate prices fell 50 percent. The bursting of the real estate bubble in the early 1990s was due largely to a number of bad loans that discouraged investment and lead to chronic deflation. Another exogenous shock to the economy occurred as a result of the Asian financial crash of 1997 that lead to widespread restructuring of corporate organizations. In the 1990s the average rate of growth was approximately one percent per year for seven of the ten years between 1991 to

–  –  –

The economic crisis has resulted in a number of studies about how Japanese organizations restructured to respond to the economic downturn.

Lincoln and Gerlach (2004) explain restructuring in terms of the network of complex ties of firms in the Japanese stakeholder model. They discuss dramatic changes in the Japanese system with the most significant being the “Big Bang” corporate governance reforms of 1997 to shake up Japan’s failing financial sector and to respond to the new realities of globalization. Deregulation promised new investment opportunities to help resolve the issue of bad loans, to create greater competition and innovation and to overhaul Japan’s faltering, hidebound system of “crony” capitalism. The reforms lead to a number of mega bank mergers and foreign direct investment in large companies throughout Japan resulting in a weakening of the stakeholder model (Lincoln and Gerlach 2004).

The most significant corporate governance reform was lifting the ban on holding companies imposed by the U.S. postwar occupation leading to increased restructuring. This new policy meant that Japanese companies could purchase dominant shares in other companies under the legal umbrella of financial and management consolidation that is widely used in the United States. But Lincoln and Gerlach conclude that on average “the process of restructuring proceeded down pathways well-carved by Japan’s distinctive historical and institutional legacies.” In a large study of Japanese firm behavior in the 1990s, Ahmadjian and Robinson (2001) show that social and institutional pressure shaped the pace and process of downsizing. Large manufacturing companies were resistant to downsizing at first but embraced it as it became more socially acceptable. In a

–  –  –

1990s tended to embrace shareholder value practices, such as downsizing and the divestiture of assets, if foreign ownership increased and if a firm’s position within the stakeholder position was weakened. If a firm however was more deeply embedded within the stakeholder system, they tended not to embrace shareholder value practices.

Vogel (2006) also reviews restructuring in Japan but sees radical change toward an American styled neo-liberal economy circumscribed by laws, practices and norms that would not only require dismantling of current institutions but the creation of new ones at all levels of the economy. His is an institutional analysis that merges rational, transaction cost approach of new institutional economics, and norms and social ties into the cost-benefit framework. Although Japanese companies sought to cut costs in the 1990s to survive within the new economic realities, they were “constrained from laying off workers, abandoning their main banks, and cutting off stable suppliers by the logic of the Japanese model itself” (p. 19). Vogel discusses “remodeling” - changes of firms within current institutions - as a more accurate interpretation of restructuring in Japan during the 1990s.

Another stream of literature focuses on the changes at the organizational level in Japan since the economic crisis. Robinson and Shimuzu (2006) analyzed the interviews and appointment calendars of 79 CEOs since 1989 and concluded that they are spending significantly more time on investor instead of bank relations and more time on external factors such as shareholder value and less time on employees, indicating a convergence towards an American style market economy. Chuma (2002) compares the economic crisis of the early 1970s to that

–  –  –

job separation and vacancy rates of recent graduates but finds dramatic personnel reductions in the 1990s “Heisei” recession compared to the oil shock of the 1970s showing that Japanese firms have incorporated downsizing practices seen in America and other liberal market economies.

Although these studies make significant contributions in understanding restructuring in Japan in the 1990s, they don’t offer an account of how or in what order changes occurred within firms when the Japanese model was challenged.

This study will attempt to add insight into the debate about restructuring in Japan through an ethnographic analysis of a single Toyota company that restructured during the Asian crash. The advantage of ethnography is that it provides a bottom-up, micro-social analysis that can be used to analyze the day to day dynamics of change. In this study I will attempt to answer such questions as: Did the old Japanese model maintain its resiliency or did the dramatic changes that occurred at the macro-level sweep away the old system? Did Toyota adopt a select number of American styled practices to adjust to change to form a hybrid system or did restructuring reflect embedded institutional practices unique to Japan to form a new model? Through vignettes of my experience as a participant observer and historical documents provided by the company, I will show that although restructuring policies were shaped by the realities of neo-liberal reforms, the outcome reflected a convergence toward a hybrid model of liberal

–  –  –

Theoretical Framework The Varieties of Capitalism An effective way to frame the restructuring discussion is through the varieties of capitalism which is an actor-centered theory that considers corporate organizations to be the critical actors in the capitalist economy (Hall and Soskice 2001). Organizations exist in a competitive space and advance their interests through strategic interaction with other firms (Scharpf 1997). Organizations adjust their behavior in the face of exogenous shocks or international competition. Their activities collectively influence the overall levels of economic performance within a national economy.

The varieties of capitalism employ a relational view of the firm. Firms must use informal or incomplete contracts to reduce problems of adverse selection and shirking. They therefore exist in a relational world in which problems must be solved through coordination with other actors. Hall and Soskice (2001) discuss five spheres of coordination – industrial relations, vocational training and education, corporate governance, inter-firm relations, and relations with employees – that are important in understanding the varieties of capitalism.

Industrial relations is important in understanding how companies coordinate bargaining over wages and working conditions with labor unions and vocational training and education is important in understanding how companies obtain and maintain a skilled workforce. Corporate governance is important in understanding how firms coordinate access to finance and how they maintain security for investor’s assurance for receiving returns on investments. Inter-firm relations are important in understanding the relationships firms have with other firms in

–  –  –

Lastly, it is important that firms coordinate problems with employees to ensure they maintain competencies and cooperate with management to advance the goals of the organization. Institutions, organizations and culture enter the into the analysis of coordination since actors generally follow both formal and informal rules for normative, cognitive or material reasons.

Scholars in the varieties of capitalism tradition fit the industrial economies into two ideal types – the liberal and coordinated market economies. In liberal market economies, firms coordinate their activities through competitive market arrangements characterized by arm’s length exchange of goods and services.



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 7 |


Similar works:

«EU Renegotiation: Fighting for a Flexible Union How to renegotiate the terms of the UK’s Membership of the EU (Quotation in title taken from President Glyn Gaskarth September 2013 ii © Civitas 2013 55 Tufton Street London SW1P 3QL Civitas is a registered charity (no. 1085494) and a company limited by guarantee, registered in England and Wales (no. 04023541) email: info@civitas.org.uk Independence: Civitas: Institute for the Study of Civil Society is a registered educational charity (No....»

«Gischlar 1 Karen L. Gischlar Department of Graduate Education, Leadership, and Counseling Rider University 2083Lawrenceville Road Lawrenceville, NJ 08648 (609) 896-7751 kgischlar@rider.edu Education Lehigh University, Bethlehem, PA Ph.D. School Psychology, APA Accredited, NASP Approved 2009 Dissertation: Efficiency and Economy in the Assessment of Emergent Literacy Skills Chair: Edward S. Shapiro, Ph.D. Rider University, Lawrenceville, NJ Ed.S. School Psychology 2003 With Distinction The...»

«Recent Developments in Financial Economics and Econometrics: An Overview* Chia-Lin Chang Department of Applied Economics Department of Finance National Chung Hsing University, Taiwan David Allen School of Accounting, Finance and Economics Edith Cowan University, Australia Michael McAleer Econometric Institute Erasmus School of Economics Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute The Netherlands and Department of Quantitative Economics Complutense University of Madrid, Spain and...»

«17 June 2014 Mr John Azarias Chairman Independent Review Panel Dear Mr. Azarias The Australian Racing Board (ARB) and Thoroughbred Breeders Australia (TBA) wish to make a joint submission to the Review Panel on behalf of the Thoroughbred industry in Australia. The industry has long had a reliance on s.457 visas to fill current labour shortages. The Australian Racing Industry Overview By way of background, the Australian Racing Board Limited (ARB) is the national body formed by and representing...»

«11 Gridlock Lobbying: Breaking, Creating, and Maintaining Legislative Stalemate Jennifer Nicoll Victor I nterest groups are permanent players in the policy-making process. They seek legislative outcomes and provide a means of representation for subsets of citizens. According to The Center for Responsive Politics, a watchdog organization that monitors lobbying and archives public data on lobbying disclosures, interest groups spent $3.27 billion lobbying the US Congress in 2008. This is up from...»

«The Origins and Evolution of Islamic Law and Finance from the bookIslamic Banking: Steady in Shaky Times? By Dr. Abdirahman Mohamed Abdi Hashi June 09, 2015 _ Editor's Note: The Origins and Evolution of Islamic Law and Finance, is a chapter from the bookIslamic Banking: Steady in Shaky Times? written By Dr. Abdirahman Mohamed. Among many topics, the book examines the stability and performance of financial institutions and if there is empirical support for the assertion that Islamic Banking are...»

«LSE Review of Books Sex and Psychopaths Celebrating 100 years of Freud’s On Narcissism Sex and Psychopaths Celebrating 100 years of Freud’s On Narcissism This e-book will look at how we can understand the apparent growth in narcissism and withdrawals from intimacy in a digital age. From the impact of Facebook and online porn on sex, to whether we’re losing the capacity to be close to the people we work with. Join us to explore whether we’re all turning into narcissists or whether we can...»

«Note: Note on Adjusted Present Value FE-NT-0264-HBS-00-E FE-NT-0264-HBS-00-E Note on Adjusted Present Value A standard procedure for evaluating a project is to forecast incremental after-tax cash flows, excluding payments to capital providers, and discount them at a weighted average cost of capital (WACC) to obtain an estimate of the project’s net present value (NPV). This note presents an alternative procedure for estimating NPV, namely the adjusted present value (APV) technique. APV is not...»

«Manual de Indicadores de Desenvolvimento Londrina 2008 1 2 Apresentação Definição do Fórum É um movimento criado por força de decreto-lei, composto por entidades e pessoas de diversos segmentos, e que tem por objetivo aglutinar a sociedade organizada e mobilizar a comunidade para o desenvolvimento sustentável de Londrina e região, por meio de atividade permanente de prospecção de futuro e planejamento estratégico, independente de política partidária. Visão de Futuro “Londrina...»

«LESOTHO Baseline Report: Worker Perspectives from the Factory and Beyond August 2012 Copyright © International Labour Organization (ILO) and International Finance Corporation (IFC) 2012 First published 2012 Publications of the ILO enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention. Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to...»

«NOTICE OF MEETING Notice is hereby given of the Meeting of the Finance and Policy Committee to be held in the Council Chamber, First Floor, Civic Administration Building, 101 Esk Street, Invercargill on Tuesday 6 September 2016 at 4.00 pm His Worship the Mayor Mr T R Shadbolt JP Cr N D Boniface (Chairman) Cr G J Sycamore (Deputy Chair) Cr R L Abbott Cr G D Lewis Cr D J Ludlow Cr L S Thomas EIRWEN HARRIS MANAGER, SECRETARIAL SERVICES 1 2 AGENDA Page 1. APOLOGIES 2. PUBLIC FORUM 3. MONITORING OF...»

«Taxing the Staff of Life: The Dutch bread tax, 1574-1855. Jan de Vries University of California at Berkeley For presentation to Yale Economic History Seminar 23 April 2012 Please do not cite without premission Shortly after the Dutch Revolt began, in 1574, the province of Holland, as it scrambled to secure revenue to conduct its war against Spain, introduced a series of excise taxes: on beer, wine, peat, slaughtered cattle, soap, fish, and on milled grain. Excise taxes had long been a familiar...»





 
<<  HOME   |    CONTACTS
2016 www.dissertation.xlibx.info - Dissertations, online materials

Materials of this site are available for review, all rights belong to their respective owners.
If you do not agree with the fact that your material is placed on this site, please, email us, we will within 1-2 business days delete him.